0 members (),
205
guests, and
28
robots. |
Key:
Admin,
Global Mod,
Mod
|
|
S |
M |
T |
W |
T |
F |
S |
|
|
|
|
|
1
|
2
|
3
|
4
|
5
|
6
|
7
|
8
|
9
|
10
|
11
|
12
|
13
|
14
|
15
|
16
|
17
|
18
|
19
|
20
|
21
|
22
|
23
|
24
|
25
|
26
|
27
|
28
|
29
|
30
|
|
|
Joined: Nov 2012
Posts: 2,513 Likes: 1
Member
|
Member
Joined: Nov 2012
Posts: 2,513 Likes: 1 |
The fixed ratio is baseless. He's implicitly assuming two things, both incorrect:
1. A fixed capital-labour ratio in all sectors and professions over time.
2. Constant total factor productivity (a proxy for technical change and the efficiency of use of factors of production-- capital, labour, natural resources, institutions, etc.) universally across industries and geographies.
As a counter example on the first, do we believe that the capital intensity of the development of biologics by doctoral biochemists requires the same capital intensity as the work of university professors of literature with doctorates, always and everywhere?
On the latter, should we believe that productivity changes in the automotive industry in New Dehli are the same as in the southern US, and eternally so? Would you explain how capital, natural resources, institutions, etc are implied/assumed in the 1:2:7 ratio of employment by type post-secondary degree? Sure. If I'm understanding your question, you want to know how these variables are included in the assumptions of fixed ratios, right? Economic output (GDP) is a function of factors of production, or inputs, that create economic value, as well as a residual factor called "total factor productivity", which measures how effectively the other inputs are used to generate output. The level of any input employed in an economy is dictated by its productivity, which determines its contribution to output. So to add some structure to this description, we can look at a generic model of the economy (you can use any of many forms, as applicable). Y = A* f{K, L, N, I, etc.}, where Y = GDP A = Total factor productivity F = Generic production function K = Capital stock L = Labour stock (Which can be a vector comprising different levels of skilled human capital, Li = [L1, L2, ... , Ln], s.t. (l1 >= l2 >= ... >= ln) N = Natural resources I = Institutions, etc. The fixed ratio of Li assumes an economy in general equilibrium. K, N, and I must then exist in fixed proportions to Li, with A constant, to maintain a uniform labour productivity for all Li across sectors, regions, and time.
What is to give light must endure burning.
|
|
|
|
Joined: Apr 2013
Posts: 5,260 Likes: 8
Member
|
OP
Member
Joined: Apr 2013
Posts: 5,260 Likes: 8 |
If I'm understanding your question, you want to know how these variables are included in the assumptions of fixed ratios, right? Not exactly. To clarify, I understand that you may disagree with the video which aeh posted. I'm trying to understand your basis for introducing the list of factors you mentioned, as a means of discrediting the author of the video (and/or discrediting the list of sources cited by the author), as "baseless". How are the factors you mentioned implied/assumed by the author and/or his cited sources? The fixed ratio is baseless. He's implicitly assuming two things, both incorrect:
1. A fixed capital-labour ratio in all sectors and professions over time.
2. Constant total factor productivity (a proxy for technical change and the efficiency of use of factors of production-- capital, labour, natural resources, institutions, etc.) universally across industries and geographies.
As a counter example on the first, do we believe that the capital intensity of the development of biologics by doctoral biochemists requires the same capital intensity as the work of university professors of literature with doctorates, always and everywhere?
On the latter, should we believe that productivity changes in the automotive industry in New Dehli are the same as in the southern US, and eternally so? Would you explain how capital, natural resources, institutions, etc are implied/assumed in the 1:2:7 ratio of employment by type post-secondary degree? Sure. If I'm understanding your question, you want to know how these variables are included in the assumptions of fixed ratios, right? Economic output (GDP) is a function of factors of production, or inputs, that create economic value, as well as a residual factor called "total factor productivity", which measures how effectively the other inputs are used to generate output. The level of any input employed in an economy is dictated by its productivity, which determines its contribution to output. So to add some structure to this description, we can look at a generic model of the economy (you can use any of many forms, as applicable). Y = A* f{K, L, N, I, etc.}, where Y = GDP A = Total factor productivity F = Generic production function K = Capital stock L = Labour stock (Which can be a vector comprising different levels of skilled human capital, Li, which is an element of [L1, L2, ... , Ln], s.t. L1 >= L2 >= ... >= Ln) N = Natural resources I = Institutions, etc. The fixed ratio of Li assumes an economy in general equilibrium. K, N, and I must then exist in fixed proportions to each Li, with A constant, to maintain a uniform labour productivity for all Li across sectors, regions, and time. I do not see that you've related this to ratio of post-secondary degrees. You are discussing productivity, which is a different topic.
|
|
|
|
Joined: Nov 2012
Posts: 2,513 Likes: 1
Member
|
Member
Joined: Nov 2012
Posts: 2,513 Likes: 1 |
The fixed ratio is baseless. He's implicitly assuming two things, both incorrect:
1. A fixed capital-labour ratio in all sectors and professions over time.
2. Constant total factor productivity (a proxy for technical change and the efficiency of use of factors of production-- capital, labour, natural resources, institutions, etc.) universally across industries and geographies.
As a counter example on the first, do we believe that the capital intensity of the development of biologics by doctoral biochemists requires the same capital intensity as the work of university professors of literature with doctorates, always and everywhere?
On the latter, should we believe that productivity changes in the automotive industry in New Dehli are the same as in the southern US, and eternally so? Would you explain how capital, natural resources, institutions, etc are implied/assumed in the 1:2:7 ratio of employment by type post-secondary degree? Sure. If I'm understanding your question, you want to know how these variables are included in the assumptions of fixed ratios, right? Economic output (GDP) is a function of factors of production, or inputs, that create economic value, as well as a residual factor called "total factor productivity", which measures how effectively the other inputs are used to generate output. The level of any input employed in an economy is dictated by its productivity, which determines its contribution to output. So to add some structure to this description, we can look at a generic model of the economy (you can use any of many forms, as applicable). Y = A* f{K, L, N, I, etc.}, where Y = GDP A = Total factor productivity F = Generic production function K = Capital stock L = Labour stock (Which can be a vector comprising different levels of skilled human capital, Li, which is an element of [L1, L2, ... , Ln], s.t. L1 >= L2 >= ... >= Ln) N = Natural resources I = Institutions, etc. The fixed ratio of Li assumes an economy in general equilibrium. K, N, and I must then exist in fixed proportions to each Li, with A constant, to maintain a uniform labour productivity for all Li across sectors, regions, and time. I do not see that you've related this to ratio of post-secondary degrees. You are discussing productivity, which is a different topic. I refer you to Li, the elements of which were defined in fixed proportions by the speaker in the video. I left their definitions deliberately general to be defined in any way desired. You could easily say l1 = 1, l2 = 2, l3 = 7 in a unit level economy. The point being, nobody should assume fixed labour proportions in making future decisions because productivity isn't static, particularly not as a universal constant.
What is to give light must endure burning.
|
|
|
|
Joined: Nov 2012
Posts: 2,513 Likes: 1
Member
|
Member
Joined: Nov 2012
Posts: 2,513 Likes: 1 |
I'm trying to understand your basis for introducing the list of factors you mentioned, as a means of discrediting the author of the video (and/or discrediting the list of sources cited by the author), as "baseless". How are the list of factors you mentioned implied/assumed by the author and/or his cited sources? Economics is the study of the allocation of scarce resources, one of which is labour. I am using a standard model from basic economic theory to disprove the author's underlying assumptions about how labour looks in equilibrium, particularly the idea that post-secondary credentialing will exist in fixed ratios across industries, regions, and time. If we are to believe he is advocating educational programming be tailored to his prescribed ratio, then students will be trained in a way that is inappropriate to the opportunities that exist for them upon completion of their studies. I hope this answers your question. If not, I'd be happy to refer you to some resources in PM that might explain the underlying models in more detail. I'd rather not write a textbook on the thread, as that is tangential to its purpose.
What is to give light must endure burning.
|
|
|
|
Joined: Apr 2013
Posts: 5,260 Likes: 8
Member
|
OP
Member
Joined: Apr 2013
Posts: 5,260 Likes: 8 |
I refer you to Li, the elements of which were defined in fixed proportions by the speaker in the video. I left their definitions deliberately general to be defined in any way desired. You could easily say l1 = 1, l2 = 2, l3 = 7 in a unit level economy. Not seeing applicability to the post-secondary degrees, sorry. The point being, nobody should assume fixed labour proportions in making future decisions because productivity isn't static, particularly not as a universal constant. What would you offer as an alternative foundation for advice in making future decisions about colleges/degrees?
|
|
|
|
Joined: Nov 2012
Posts: 2,513 Likes: 1
Member
|
Member
Joined: Nov 2012
Posts: 2,513 Likes: 1 |
I refer you to Li, the elements of which were defined in fixed proportions by the speaker in the video. I left their definitions deliberately general to be defined in any way desired. You could easily say l1 = 1, l2 = 2, l3 = 7 in a unit level economy. Not seeing applicability to the post-secondary degrees, sorry. The point being, nobody should assume fixed labour proportions in making future decisions because productivity isn't static, particularly not as a universal constant. What would you offer as an alternative foundation for advice in making future decisions about colleges/degrees? Li is a vector of factor endowments of different types of human capital; a head count, if you will, of the different levels of employees with each type of credential. My recommendation? Assume general equilibrium is unique to the region, industry, and time in which economic activity is generated. Let labour be assigned as much capital as it needs as merited by its marginal productivity (i.e. let that level fluctuate according to demand) and let enrollment levels in post-secondary programs be as market-linked as possible, with intervention only when there is a strong public policy argument. Sorry, I get jargony quickly and forget my audience sometimes!
What is to give light must endure burning.
|
|
|
|
Joined: Apr 2013
Posts: 5,260 Likes: 8
Member
|
OP
Member
Joined: Apr 2013
Posts: 5,260 Likes: 8 |
Economics is the study of the allocation of scarce resources, one of which is labour. Yes, however there is not a scarcity of labor... this is the raison d'être for the video. Helping the new generation of students begin planning now to increase the odds that they will not be unemployed/underemployed or invest time and money in "any" degree which they may learn after-the-fact is not applicable to their strengths and/or to positions available in the job market. I am using a standard model from basic economic theory to disprove Mathematical models change over time, and may not be a good "fit" for every situation. I have questioned whether it is a good "fit" here. the author's underlying assumptions about how labour looks in equilibrium particularly the idea that post-secondary credentialing will exist in fixed ratios across industries, regions, and time. Not that post-secondary credentialing will exist in fixed ratios (as though the production of degrees is being limited/controlled), but that the job market calls for skills in a ratio of 1:2:7. Regions were not discussed, and the time span discussed was 80 years. I'd rather not write a textbook on the thread, as that is tangential to its purpose. If we could see that the model was a good "fit" for the video, the model would be on-topic. The 1:2:7 ratio (whose source he cited) may not be correct, but the model you've introduced does not seem to prove it false. If we are to believe he is advocating educational programming be tailored to his prescribed ratio, then students will be trained in a way that is inappropriate to the opportunities that exist for them upon completion of their studies. I do not believe that he has advocated for educational programming to be tailored to a ratio (ie: limit/control the number of each type of degree which can be conferred), rather he has suggested what course of action consumers in a free market may most benefit from personally. He has clearly advocated for empowering consumers with information so that their enrollment choices in post-secondary programs are as market-linked as possible. Some may say you agree, at least in part, with his recommendations.
|
|
|
|
Joined: Nov 2012
Posts: 2,513 Likes: 1
Member
|
Member
Joined: Nov 2012
Posts: 2,513 Likes: 1 |
Indigo, several of those are reasonable questions. Short of turning this thread into a second year macroeconomics lecture, which I'm sure won't earn me any friends (they don't call us dismal scientists for nothing ), I'm happy to point you in the direction of this book: it discusses the broad tools required to answer them at a high level. I highly recommend it; it's succinct and well written (I have a copy on my shelf). http://www.amazon.ca/Macroeconomic-Theory-A-Short-Course/dp/0765611422For an empirical validation of my first post and initial explanation to you, I'd recommend searching the Federal Reserve site for research on labour market dynamics. They'll have current numbers published across industries with forward-looking estimates and their rationale. You don't have to trust any models to see that different industries and professions have different productivities, requiring a different labour mix, counter to the opinions offered in the linked video.
What is to give light must endure burning.
|
|
|
|
Joined: Apr 2013
Posts: 5,260 Likes: 8
Member
|
OP
Member
Joined: Apr 2013
Posts: 5,260 Likes: 8 |
different industries and professions have different productivities, requiring a different labour mix. The video mentioned industries, not professions. Industries are different than professions. Industries contain a large cross-section of professions, a broad array of qualifications and post-secondary education. Some may say there is continuous scope creep with you introducing regions, professions, and other items which were not a part the video, rather than discussing what was actually said in the video.
|
|
|
|
Joined: Mar 2013
Posts: 1,453
Member
|
Member
Joined: Mar 2013
Posts: 1,453 |
Become what you are
|
|
|
|
|